We will often want a measure for the amount of benefit someone receives from a market transaction (such as a purchase.) In the world of demand, a simple effective measure can be constructed using consumer’s willingness to pay. Consider our mountain bike enthusiast friends from earlier.
\(WTP\)
Kyle
$375
Tara
$300
Kate
$270
Aaron
$175
If the price in the market is $275, we know that Kyle and Tara will both buy a bike, so \(Q_D = 2\text{.}\) How much does each consumer benefit? Start with Kyle. He was willing to pay $375, but only was asked to pay a price of $275 for the bike. In one sense, then, Kyle receives a benefit of $100. It’s extra money Kyle has in his pocket that he would have paid had the price been higher but does not actually pay, referred to as Kyle’s consumer surplus. Consumer surplus can be calculated as the difference between a consumer’s WTP and the price the consumer actually pays. Similarly, then, Tara receives a consumer surplus of $25. The two consumers who do not buy, Kate and Aaron, each get a consumer surplus of zero. Therefore, at a price of $275, there is $125 of total consumer surplus in the market - $100 goes to Kyle and $25 goes to Tara.
\(WTP\)
\(P\)
Consumer Surplus
Kyle
$375
$275
$100
Tara
$300
$275
$25
Kate
$270
$275
$0
Aaron
$175
$275
$0
Consumer surplus in the market for mountain bikes when \(P = \$275\)
Consumer surplus does not go negative for Kate or Aaron. If Kate were to buy the bike, for example, she would pay a price of $275 for a bike which she values at $270, which would (hypothetically) give her a “benefit” of -$5. Actually a loss! So instead, as we have shown, Kate chooses not to buy, avoiding the loss and earning a consumer surplus of zero.
Figure1.4.1.Consumer surplus in the market for mountain bikes when \(P = \$275\)
Graphically, consumer surplus (CS) can be seen as the vertical distance underneath the demand curve but above the price. With a stepwise demand curve, this is a triangular-ish area underneath the staircase. The far left column is the (large) benefit to the consumer with the highest WTP, and the next column down gives the smaller benefit to the next highest WTP consumer. There is no benefit to the third and fourth consumers since they do not buy.
Checkpoint1.4.2.
You and your two friends go out for ramen for lunch one day. The spicy garlic miso ramen sells for $12 on the menu. The table below provides the willingness to pay (WTP) values for each of you for spicy garlic miso ramen.
Use this information to find: 1. your consumer surplus and 2. the total for you and your friends.
\(WTP\)
You
$20
Alice
$14
Isaiah
$10
Hint.
With stepwise demand such as this, each unit has its own amount of consumer surplus.
Answer.
1. You \(CS= WTP - P = 20 - 12 = 8\text{.}\) So the ramen is worth $8 more to you than you have to pay.
2. Total CS: \((20 - 12) + (14 - 12)= 10\text{.}\) You and Alice get a total of $10 CS. Isaiah gets 0 because his WTP is below the price, right?
With more consumers, the same approach can be taken, though the columns under the demand curve get smaller and smaller. What about if there are many consumers? Ultimately, with a smooth demand curve, the consumer surplus would measure the total benefit in the market going to consumers. Since the steps have been smoothed out, so too are the columns of CS: consumer surplus then becomes the area of the triangle under the demand curve and above the price. Despite the different shape, consumer surplus still illustrates the large benefit for the highest WTP consumers, and the very small benefit to the low-but-still-willing-to-buy consumers (WTP of $25.01, price of $25). Moreover, once again, the section of demand to the right of \(Q_D\) captures all of the consumers who are not willing to pay at that price and who receive no benefit.
Figure1.4.3.Consumer surplus with smooth demand curve \(Q_D = 100 - 2P\) when \(P = \$25\)
Checkpoint1.4.4.
Use the smooth demand curve shown in Figure 1.4.3 to find consumer surplus if \(P=30\text{.}\)
Hint.
Note that you will need the information in the graph and the corresponding demand function, \(Q_{D}=100 - 2P\text{,}\) to find consumer surplus.
Answer.
First, we need to find the quantity demanded at the price of $30. To do so, we plug this into the demand function.
Since the consumer surplus here is geometrically a triangle, we use the area of a triangle formula to solve. \(Area = \frac{1}{2}bh\) Where b is base and h is height.
The height is the difference between the vertical intercept, here 50, and the price we are interested in, here 30.